APPENDIX
B
The Eects of the 2017Tax Act on CBO’s
Economic and Budget Projections
Overview
In December2017, Public Law 115-97, referred to here
as the 2017tax act, was enacted. e act made import-
ant changes to the tax system that apply to both busi-
nesses and individuals. Consequently, the Congressional
Budget Oce had to estimate its eects when preparing
its new baseline projections, which incorporate the
assumption that current laws aecting taxes and spend-
ing generally do not change. In those projections for the
2018–2028period, the act’s changes boost economic
output and increase budget decits, on net.
What Are the Act’s Major Provisions?
e 2017tax act changes corporate and individual tax
rates and includes various provisions that aect how
businesses and individuals calculate their taxable income.
Among other things, the act lowers the top corporate
income tax rate to 21percent. It changes the way that
the foreign income of U.S. corporations is taxed, and it
reduces some incentives for corporations to shift prots
outside the United States. For the next eight years, the
act lowers individual income tax rates and broadens the
total amount of income subject to that tax. Also for the
next eight years, it increases the tax exemptions for prop-
erty transferred at death and for certain gifts. Starting
next year, it eliminates the penalty for not having health
insurance—a penalty imposed under a provision of the
Aordable Care Act generally called the individual man-
date. And it changes the measure of ination that is used
to adjust certain tax parameters.
What Are the Act’s Projected Economic Eects?
In CBO’s assessment, the 2017tax act changes busi-
nesses’ and individuals’ incentives in various ways. On
net, those changes are expected to encourage saving,
investment, and work.
CBO projects that the act’s eects on the U.S. economy
over the 2018–2028period will include higher levels
of investment, employment, and gross domestic prod-
uct (GDP). For example, in CBO’s projections, the act
boosts average annual real GDP by 0.7percent over the
2018–2028period. Analysis of the act’s economic eects
is complicated by its mix of permanent and temporary
provisions; of particular note is that it lowers the corpo-
rate income tax rate permanently but individual income
tax rates only through 2025. As a result, the projected
economic eects vary over the 11-year period; the largest
eects on the economy occur during the period’s middle
years.
CBO’s projections of the act’s economic eects are based
partly on projections of the act’s eects on potential
GDP—the economy’s maximum sustainable level of
production. In the agency’s projections, the act increases
the level of potential GDP by boosting investment and
labor. By lowering the corporate income tax rate, the act
gives businesses incentives to increase investment, and
by lowering individual income tax rates through 2025,
it gives people incentives to increase their participation
in the labor force and their hours worked, expanding the
potential labor supply and employment. Other provi-
sions of the tax act, including a limit on deductions for
state and local taxes and for mortgage interest, will push
down residential investment, but the overall eect on
investment is positive. One result of the act will dampen
those positive eects on potential output: It will increase
federal decits and therefore increase federal borrowing
and interest rates, crowding out some private investment.
In CBO’s projections, the act initially boosts real GDP
(that is, GDP adjusted to remove the eects of ina-
tion) in relation to real potential GDP, inuencing other
economic variables, such as ination and interest rates.
GDP is pushed up in relation to potential GDP because
the act increases overall demand for goods and services
(by raising households’ and businesses’ after-tax income).
e heightened economic activity subsequently generates
more demand for labor and consequently higher wages.
In response, the labor force participation rate (which is
the percentage of people in the civilian noninstitutional-
ized population who are at least 16years old and either
Appendix B
106 The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028 APRIL 2018
working or seeking work) rises, as do the number of
hours worked, and the unemployment rate goes down.
e largest positive eects occur during the 2018–
2023period. After income tax rates rise as scheduled at
the close of 2025, the growth of overall demand is damp-
ened in relation to the growth of potential output.
Among the eects of the initially stronger output growth
are slightly higher ination and an increase in the
exchange value of the dollar. Furthermore, CBO expects
the Federal Reserve to respond to the stronger labor
market and increases in inationary pressure by pushing
short-term interest rates higher over the next few years.
Long-term interest rates are also expected to rise.
Just as the tax act is projected to boost real GDP, it
is expected to increase income for labor and business
over the 2018–2028period. e act will also aect
the relationship between GDP and gross national
product (GNP). GNP diers from GDP by includ-
ing the income that U.S. residents earn from abroad
and excluding the income that nonresidents earn from
domestic sources; it is therefore a better measure of
the income available to U.S. residents. Because the act
reduces the amount of net foreign income earned by
U.S. residents in CBO’s projections, it increases GNP
less than it increases GDP.
What Are the Act’s Projected Budgetary Eects?
To construct its baseline budget projections, CBO incor-
porated the eects of the tax act, taking into account
economic feedback—that is, the ways in which the act
is likely to aect the economy and in turn aect the
budget. Doing so raised the 11-year projection of the
cumulative primary decit (that is, the decit excluding
the costs of servicing the debt) by $1.3trillion and raised
projected debt-service costs by roughly $600billion. e
act therefore increases the total projected decit over the
2018–2028period by about $1.9trillion.
Before taking economic feedback into account, CBO
estimated that the tax act would increase the primary
decit by $1.8trillion and debt-service costs by roughly
$450billion. e feedback is estimated to lower the
cumulative primary decit by about $550billion, mostly
because the act is projected to increase taxable income
and thus push tax revenues up. And that feedback raises
projected debt-service costs, because even though the
reduction in primary decits means that less borrowing
is necessary, the act is expected to result in higher interest
rates on debt, which are projected to more than oset the
eects on debt-service costs of the smaller debt. On net,
economic feedback from the act raises debt-service costs
in CBO’s projections by about $100billion.
What Uncertainty Surrounds CBO’s Estimates?
CBO’s estimates of the economic and budgetary eects
of the 2017tax act are subject to a good deal of uncer-
tainty. e agency is uncertain about various issues—for
example, the way the act will be implemented by the
Treasury; how households and businesses will rearrange
their nances in the face of the act; and how households,
businesses, and foreign investors will respond to changes
in incentives to work, save, and invest in the United
States. at uncertainty implies that the actual outcomes
may dier substantially from the projected ones.
The Major Provisions of the Act
e 2017tax act makes important changes to the tax sys-
tem that apply to both businesses and individuals. ey
include changes to corporate and individual tax rates
and a variety of provisions that aect how businesses and
individuals calculate their taxable income. e changes
have important eects on incentives to save, invest, and
work.
Together, CBO estimates, the act’s provisions reduce,
on net, the user cost of capital, which is the gross
pretax return on investment that provides the required
return to investors after covering taxes and depreci-
ation. at required return can be thought of as the
return that investors would have received if they had
used their funds to make another, equally risky invest-
ment. erefore, all things being equal, as the user
cost of capital falls, investment rises, and vice versa. In
addition, the smaller user cost of capital implies lower
eective marginal tax rates on capital income.
1
By CBO’s
1. e eective marginal tax rate on capital income is the share of
the return on an additional investment made in a particular year
that will be paid in taxes over the life of that investment. Unlike
statutory tax rates, eective marginal tax rates account for the
tax treatment of depreciation and various other features of the
tax code. For descriptions of CBO’s method of estimating the
eective marginal tax rate on capital income, see Congressional
Budget Oce, Taxing Capital Income: Eective Marginal Tax
Rates Under 2014 Law and Selected Policy Options (December
2014), Appendix A, www.cbo.gov/publication/49817, and
Computing Eective Tax Rates on Capital Income (December
2006), www.cbo.gov/publication/18259. For a description of
the relationship between the eective marginal tax rate and the
user cost of capital, see page 30of the December 2014 report,
in which the user cost of capital is found by summing the real
before-tax rate of return required to cover certain costs (ρ) and
the rate of depreciation (δ).
107appendiX B: The eFFecTS oF The 2017TaX acT on cBo’S economic and BudgeT proJecTionS The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028
estimate, the act reduces the eective marginal tax rate
on capital income, averaged over all types of investment,
by between 1.4percentage points and 3.4percentage
points from 2018 to 2028 (see Table B-1). at in turn
stimulates personal saving.
In addition, CBO estimates that the act reduces, on
net, the eective marginal tax rate on labor income by
2.2percentage points in 2018 and by slightly smaller
amounts through 2025, thereby encouraging work.
2
Beginning in 2026, the act is projected to boost the rate,
2. e eective marginal tax rate on labor income is the share
of an additional dollar of such income that is unavailable to a
worker because it is paid in federal individual income taxes and
payroll taxes or oset by reductions in benets from government
programs. at rate, like the eective marginal tax rate on capital
income, diers from statutory tax rates by taking into account
dierent features of the tax code (for example, the gradual
reduction in the value of the earned income tax credit as income
rises). For more information on how changes in after-tax wages
distort incentives to work, see Robert McClelland and Shannon
Mok, A Review of Recent Research on Labor Supply Elasticities,
Working Paper 2012-12 (Congressional Budget Oce, October
2012), www.cbo.gov/publication/43675.
as temporary measures that lower it expire and provisions
that push it up continue.
Changing the Corporate Income Tax Rate
Before the act was passed, businesses subject to the
corporate income tax faced a graduated rate structure.
e statutory tax rates were 15percent, 25percent,
34percent, and 35percent, depending on the business’s
income. e act replaces that structure with a single rate
of 21percent, beginning in 2018. at change lowers,
on average, the tax rate paid by businesses subject to the
corporate income tax. e change also contributes to
the reduction of the eective marginal tax rate on capital
income.
e corporate income tax distorts domestic economic
incentives, aecting the decisions made by corporations
and investors.
3
In addition, variation among the cor-
porate tax systems of dierent countries distorts deci-
sions about where to locate international investment.
3. For more information on how the corporate income tax distorts
economic incentives, see Congressional Budget Oce, Corporate
Income Tax Rates: International Comparisons (November 2005),
pp. 1–9, www.cbo.gov/publication/17501.
Table B-1 .
Projections of Eective Marginal Federal Tax Rates
Percent
2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028
Labor Income
Rate Under Prior Law 29.4 29.5 29.7 29.8 30.0 30.1 30.2 30.4 30.5 30.6 30.7
Rate Under the 2017 Tax Act 27.2 27.4 27.6 27.7 27.9 28.1 28.2 28.5 30.6 30.7 30.8
Dierence (Percentage points) -2.2 -2.2 -2.2 -2.1 -2.1 -2.0 -1.9 -1.9 * 0.1 0.1
Capital Income
Rate Under Prior Law 16.5 16.8 17.9 17.9 17.9 17.9 17.9 17.9 17.9 18.0 18.0
Rate Under the 2017 Tax Act 14.7 14.7 14.6 14.5 15.4 15.7 16.1 16.5 16.0 16.5 16.5
Dierence (Percentage points) -1.8 -2.1 -3.3 -3.4 -2.5 -2.2 -1.9 -1.4 -1.9 -1.5 -1.5
Source: Congressional Budget Oce.
The eective marginal tax rate on labor income is the share of an additional dollar of such income that is unavailable to a worker because it is paid in
federal individual income taxes and payroll taxes or oset by reductions in benefits from government programs, averaged among workers with weights
proportional to their labor income.
The eective marginal tax rate on capital income is the share of the return on an additional investment made in a particular year that will be paid
in taxes over the life of that investment. The before- and after-tax rates of return used to calculate that eective tax rate are weighted averages of
the rates for every combination of asset type, industry, form of organization, and source of nancing; the weights used are the asset values of each
combination. All of those rates of return incorporate estimated values for interest rates on corporate debt, rates of inflation, and returns paid by
Ccorporations on equity that are consistent with recent trends and with CBO’s economic forecast. Specifically, CBO has incorporated a nominal interest
rate on debt for corporate securities of 5.8 percent; a rate of inflation, measured by the price index for urban consumers, of 2.4 percent; and a real
return on equity of 5.2 percent.
* = between zero and 0.05 percentage points.
108 The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028 APRIL 2018
Reducing the corporate income tax rate in the United
States reduces those distortions in several important
ways. First, it reduces the pretax return required to
induce businesses to invest. at reduces the user cost of
capital and should therefore increase investment. Second,
it makes debt nancing less advantageous in relation to
equity nancing—because businesses may deduct the
interest on debt from their taxable income, and the value
of that deduction becomes smaller when tax rates are
lower. ird, the reduction in corporate income taxes
increases U.S. and foreign investors’ incentives to invest
and to locate activities in the United States rather than
abroad.
4
Fourth, it reduces the incentive to shift income
from the United States to lower-tax countries.
Changing International Taxes
e act changes how the United States taxes the foreign
income of U.S. corporations. It also imposes a onetime
tax on previously untaxed foreign prots. And it adds
measures to discourage prot shifting, a practice in
which multinational corporations lower their tax liabili-
ties by shifting reported taxable income from aliates in
countries with higher corporate tax rates to aliates in
countries with lower ones.
Changing the Taxation of Foreign Income. ere are
two broad ways in which a country may tax the foreign
income earned by a domestic corporation. Under a pure
worldwide system, any foreign income is taxed immedi-
ately by the corporation’s home country. Under a pure
territorial system, the corporation’s home country does
not tax foreign income at all.
5
Under prior law, the United States had a system that
more closely resembled worldwide taxation. However,
only some types of foreign income—generally those
that the government regarded as being passive (such as
interest income) or highly mobile—were taxed as the
income was earned. Taxes on many types of foreign
4. For more information about those incentives, see Congressional
Budget Oce, Taxing Capital Income: Eective Marginal Tax
Rates Under 2014 Law and Selected Policy Options (December
2014), www.cbo.gov/publication/49817. For more information
about location decisions, see Congressional Budget Oce,
International Comparisons of Corporate Income Tax Rates (March
2017), www.cbo.gov/publication/52419.
5. For a more detailed description of both approaches, see
Congressional Budget Oce, Options for Taxing U.S.
Multinational Corporations (January 2013), www.cbo.gov/
publication/43764.
income earned by a U.S. corporation’s foreign subsidiary
were deferred until the income was repatriated—that is,
distributed to the U.S. parent company. Earnings were
considered repatriated if, for example, they were paid out
to shareholders as dividends, used to buy back shares,
or used to fund an investment in physical capital in the
United States.
e 2017tax act replaces that approach with a system
that may more closely resemble territorial taxation.
Dividends that a U.S. parent company receives from
its foreign subsidiaries will now be exempt from U.S.
taxation. However, foreign income that the government
regards as passive or highly mobile will still be taxed as
the income is earned.
Because the repatriation of foreign earnings triggered
tax liability under prior law, some corporations behaved
as though they were constrained in how they could
use foreign earnings. e new dividend exemption will
eliminate that constraint. As a result, corporations will
probably repatriate a larger share of their foreign earnings
by reducing the amount that they reinvest in foreign
economies.
However, the dividend exemption is anticipated to
encourage some further prot shifting, because corpora-
tions that shift prots from the United States to lower-
tax countries can now repatriate them without paying
taxes. at increase in prot shifting will reduce the
amount of income subject to U.S. taxes.
Onetime Tax on Previously Untaxed Foreign
Prots.e tax act also addresses the treatment of undis-
tributed foreign earnings that accumulated before the
taxation of foreign income was changed (see Box B-1).
It imposes a tax on those undistributed foreign earn-
ings, with separate rates for cash assets (15.5percent)
and noncash assets (8percent). Corporations must pay
the tax regardless of whether they actually repatriate
the earnings to the United States—a requirement often
called “deemed repatriation”—and have the option of
spreading the payment of the tax over eight years. e
tax should have only a limited eect on the decisions
that corporations make, because it applies only to their
existing stock of foreign earnings.
Measures to Reduce Prot Shifting. e act con-
tains several provisions to reduce corporations’ incen-
tive to shift prots out of the United States. Two
109appendiX B: The eFFecTS oF The 2017TaX acT on cBo’S economic and BudgeT proJecTionS The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028
provisions—which impose a tax on global intangible
low-tax income (GILTI) and create a deduction for
foreign- derived intangible income (FDII)—reduce cor-
porations’ incentive to locate high-return assets (which
are often intangible assets, such as intellectual property,
or IP) in low-tax countries. e provisions reduce that
incentive by applying special treatment to prots that
exceed a specied return on tangible assets (such as
equipment and structures).
6
6. e GILTI provision imposes a tax on foreign income that
exceeds a 10percent return on foreign tangible assets if a
In addition to reducing prot shifting through the
location of intangible assets, the GILTI and FDII
provisions aect corporations’ decisions about where to
locate tangible assets. By locating more tangible assets
abroad, a corporation is able to reduce the amount of
foreign income that is categorized as GILTI. Similarly,
by locating fewer tangible assets in the United States, a
multinational corporation’s average foreign tax rate is below a
certain threshold. e FDII deduction applies to U.S. prots that
exceed a 10percent return on U.S. tangible assets. e deduction
is proportional to the share of U.S. income that is derived from
foreign sales.
Box B-1 .
Repatriation of Undistributed Foreign Earnings
Before the 2017 tax act was enacted, a multinational corpo-
ration (MNC) could defer paying taxes on foreign earnings
until they were distributed to the MNC’s parent company in
the United States. Earnings were considered distributed if, for
example, they were paid out to shareholders as dividends,
used to buy back shares, or used to fund an investment
in physical capital in the United States. To avoid the tax
cost, MNCs left large amounts of earnings in their foreign
subsidiaries—a total of $2.6 trillion as of 2015, according to the
sta of the Joint Committee on Taxation.
1
The 2017 tax act mandates “deemed repatriation” for those
accumulated foreign earnings, which means that MNCs will pay
U.S. taxes on the earnings even if they are not distributed to
the United States. The act thus eliminates the tax disincentive
to distribute those earnings. As a result, MNCs are expected
to end up deploying the earnings in their domestic operations
more often.
The Congressional Budget Oce projects that deemed repa-
triation will have some eects on MNCs’ financial decisions.
Before the change in law, some MNCs, to avoid paying the
tax cost of using foreign earnings to fund investments and
payments to shareholders, used borrowed funds for those
purposes, in CBO’s judgment. Because MNCs can no longer
avoid the tax cost, CBO projects that some will reduce their
borrowing. Also, some of the previously undistributed earnings
can be paid to shareholders through share repurchases and
larger dividends.
1. Thomas A. Barthold, Joint Committee on Taxation, letter to the Honorable
Kevin Brady, Chairman, House Ways and Means Committee, and the
Honorable Richard Neal (August 31, 2016), https://go.usa.gov/xQrVY.
On the whole, however, CBO projects that the economic
eects of deemed repatriation will be small. The MNCs that
refrained from distributing their foreign earnings tended to
be established corporations in the high-tech sector that faced
low costs in funding domestic activities and probably did not
forgo worthy investments as a result of keeping their earnings
undistributed. Furthermore, even though the term “repatria-
tion” suggests that the undistributed funds will return to the
United States from abroad, they are often already invested
in dollar-denominated xed-income securities issued by U.S.
borrowers. The funds are outside the United States only in
the sense of being owned by a foreign subsidiary of a U.S.
corporation. In fact, MNCs have held a substantial fraction
of their undistributed funds as long-term Treasury securities,
CBO estimates. Finally, over the past decade, MNCs have paid
large amounts of cash to their shareholders through share
repurchases even as they have kept earnings undistributed,
so it is unlikely that the foreign earnings represent pent-up
dividends or investments waiting to happen.
In CBO’s projections, the eects of deemed repatriation on
MNCs’ financial decisions lead to a small decrease in the cor-
porate spread, which is the dierence between corporate and
U.S. government interest rates. Corporations are expected to
reduce their holdings of U.S. government debt and reduce their
borrowing. As they reduce holdings of federal debt, interest
rates for it will rise; meanwhile, as they borrow less, interest
rates for corporate debt will fall. The resulting decrease in
the corporate spread should support additional corporate
investment but put some upward pressure on the interest rates
of Treasury notes.
110 The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028 APRIL 2018
corporation can increase the amount of U.S. income that
can be deducted as FDII. Together, the provisions may
increase corporations’ incentive to locate tangible assets
abroad. (Like prot shifting, such decisions change the
locations of reported prots—but they are not classied
as prot shifting, because they involve actual economic
activity rather than simply reporting.)
Another provision, the base erosion and antiabuse tax
(BEAT), limits the ability of both U.S. and foreign
multinational corporations to use related-party transac-
tions to shift prots from the United States to lower-tax
countries. (Related-party transactions are transactions
between the aliates of a multinational corporation.)
BEAT imposes a minimum tax on relatively large multi-
national corporations, which must pay the larger of two
amounts: their regular tax liability, and a tax at a spec-
ied rate (generally 10percent) on a broader measure
of U.S. taxable income that is adjusted for related-party
transactions.
Changing the Taxation of Domestic Business Activity
e 2017tax act makes numerous changes to tax
provisions that aect both corporate and noncorporate
businesses. ose changes limit or eliminate some tax
preferences and thus increase the tax base (that is, the
total amount of income subject to tax); provide incen-
tives for certain types of investments by allowing busi-
nesses to deduct the costs more rapidly; and create a new
deduction for certain owners of pass-through businesses
(which are businesses whose prots are taxed not directly
through the corporate income tax but when their owners
pay income tax on their share of prots).
7
On net, those
changes reduce the eective marginal tax rate on capital
income paid by corporate and noncorporate businesses.
Base Expansion. e act expands the business income
tax base in a number of ways. One is a new limit on net
interest deductions; another modies the treatment of
losses.
Interest Limit. Under prior law, a business could generally
deduct its interest expense when calculating its taxable
income. For businesses whose gross receipts are greater
than $25 million, the act limits the deduction of interest
7. For more information, see “Key Methods at CBO Used
to Estimate the Macroeconomic Eects of the 2017 Tax Act”
(supplemental material for e Budget and Economic Outlook:
2018 to 2028, April 2018), https://go.usa.gov/xQcZD.
expense to an amount equal to a business’s interest
income plus 30 percent of its adjusted taxable income.
e measure of adjusted taxable income used for that
determination excludes interest income and expense. It
also excludes deductions for depreciation and similar
costs through 2021but then includes them. Business
interest that is not deducted because it exceeds the limit
may be carried forward—that is, potentially claimed
in a future year. Special rules apply to pass-through
businesses.
Limiting the deductibility of interest creates an incen-
tive to reduce existing debt and reduces the incentive to
issue new debt, particularly for companies that already
have substantial amounts of debt. Limiting interest
deductions may also increase multinational corporations’
incentive to borrow through aliates that are not in
the United States instead of through aliates that are.
at would increase prots reported by aliates that
are in the United States. In addition, the change in the
denition of adjusted taxable income in 2022lowers
businesses’ capacity to deduct interest, encouraging larger
investment and depreciation deductions before 2022.
Limits on the Use of Net Operating Losses. Under prior
law, a net operating loss could be deducted from tax-
able income up to 2years in the past and up to 20years
in the future. For losses occurring after 2017, the act
restricts the deduction to future income (for most
industries), and it restricts the deduction to 80percent of
taxable income. In addition, the 20-year limit is repealed.
For the owners of pass-through businesses, trade or
business losses can be used to oset current-year income
from other sources. e act limits that current-year
deduction to $500,000annually for joint returns and
$250,000 for single returns. Any excess loss can be
deducted as a net operating loss in the future.
Overall, those provisions treat losses less generously
than prior law did. Restricting the deduction of losses to
future income will mean that companies will no longer
be able to use losses in a way that creates a current-year
refund. at change may especially hurt corporations
without many liquid assets. In addition, the changes
reduce corporations’ incentive to claim various deduc-
tions that can result in losses.
Deductions for Capital Investments. When a business
invests in a tangible asset, it generally deducts the cost
111appendiX B: The eFFecTS oF The 2017TaX acT on cBo’S economic and BudgeT proJecTionS The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028
of the investment over time until it has deducted the
full purchase price of the asset. For each type of asset,
tax law and regulations prescribe a depreciation schedule
that determines the amount to be deducted each year.
Under certain circumstances, however, the cost of the
asset can be fully “expensed”—that is, fully deducted in
the year it is placed in service. e 2017tax act expands
those circumstances for many types of tangible assets but
restricts them for certain intangible ones—specically,
research and development (R&D) and software devel-
opment. It increases the base amount of tangible equip-
ment that can be expensed under section 179 of the tax
code to $1million, and it increases the base amount
of investment at which that expensing begins to phase
out to $2.5million. e act also temporarily increases
the percentage of the investment in new tangible equip-
ment that businesses can expense from 50percent of the
acquisition cost to 100percent; between 2023 and 2027,
that “bonus depreciation” will be phased down to zero
in 20-percentage-point increments.
8
In contrast, invest-
ment in R&D and software development must now be
deducted in equal proportions over ve years if the costs
are incurred in 2022or later; in the past, that investment
could be expensed.
e speed with which businesses can deduct their capital
spending aects the pretax rate of return needed to
induce a new investment; it thus aects the user cost of
capital as well. Expensing reduces the user cost of capital
by allowing businesses to deduct the cost of investment
from their taxable income more quickly. e expansion
of expensing for tangible assets should result in more
investment in the qualifying types of assets. However,
those types were already treated more favorably than
nonqualifying types of tangible assets (mostly buildings),
and the expansion of expensing will widen that disparity.
e result will be some distortion in favor of the quali-
fying types. Requiring R&D and software development
costs to be deducted over ve years rather than imme-
diately will increase the cost of capital and thus reduce
those types of investment.
Deduction for Certain Owners of Pass-rough
Businesses. e prots of pass-through businesses are
allocated to their owners, added to their taxable income,
and often taxed through the individual income tax.
8. e bonus depreciation percentage was 50percent in 2017;
under prior law, it was scheduled to be 40percent in 2018,
30percent in 2019, and zero thereafter.
e rate at which those prots are taxed consequently
depends on which tax bracket the owner is in. rough
2025, individual income tax rates are generally lower
under the 2017tax act than they would have been under
prior law, but not by nearly as much as the corporate
income tax rate. However, the act also provides a tem-
porary new deduction to many owners of pass-through
businesses through 2025. e deduction is equal to
20percent of qualied business income, which includes
the reasonable compensation of owners for services
rendered to the business. Eligibility for the deduction
depends on both the owner’s income and the nature of
the business. e deduction phases out with income for
owners of personal-service businesses (such as law rms,
medical practices, and consulting rms). For other own-
ers, the deduction may be limited by the wages that the
business pays and the property that it owns.
Because it has the same eect as a reduction in the tax
rate, the deduction for pass-through businesses lowers
the cost of capital for qualifying companies and reduces
the disparity between the tax treatments of debt- and
equity-nanced investment. It also reduces the disparity
between the treatments of capital income earned by cor-
porations and of capital income earned by pass-through
businesses. However, it may result in dierent tax rates
for dierent sources of labor income. at dierence
could occur because the deduction gives owners of pass-
through businesses an incentive to underreport their
reasonable compensation—a tactic that has been used
successfully to avoid self-employment taxes in the past
and that is not available to wage earners. In addition,
the deduction’s dierent treatment of dierent industries
could further aect economic decisions.
Changing Individual Income Taxes
e 2017tax act changes individual income taxes,
lowering statutory tax rates but also broadening the tax
base through various provisions. On net, the act reduces
marginal tax rates: Provisions that reduce statutory rates
and expand the standard deduction push marginal rates
down, an eect only partly oset by provisions that limit
itemized deductions and eliminate personal exemptions.
Most of the provisions involving individual income taxes
expire at the end of 2025. e temporary nature of those
provisions will aect the behavior of some taxpayers;
they will try to earn more during the years when rates
are lower or to delay deductible expenses—whose value
rises as rates increase—until after 2025. Many other
112 The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028 APRIL 2018
taxpayers will not change their behavior as a result of the
provisions’ temporary nature. at might occur because
they cannot change the timing of their taxable income,
because they expect policymakers to permanently extend
the provisions, or because they are unaware of the expira-
tion dates.
Temporary Reduction in Individual Income Tax Rates.
Under prior law, taxable ordinary income earned by most
individuals was subject to the following seven statutory
rates: 10percent, 15percent, 25percent, 28percent,
33percent, 35percent, and 39.6percent.
9
Dierent
rates applied to dierent brackets of people’s taxable
ordinary income. e 2017tax act retains the seven-rate
structure but reduces most of the rates; the new rates are
10percent, 12percent, 22percent, 24percent, 32per-
cent, 35percent, and 37percent. e act also expands
the width of the brackets, increasing the number of
taxpayers subject to lower rates.
e lower tax rates are projected to increase the supply
of labor.
10
Because they will increase after-tax returns on
investment, they are also anticipated to boost investment
by pass-through businesses, which are taxed through the
individual income tax.
11
Temporary Reduction in the Amount of Income
Subject to the Alternative Minimum Tax. Some tax-
payers are subject to the alternative minimum tax
(AMT), which was intended to impose taxes on higher-
income people who use tax preferences to greatly reduce
or even eliminate their liability under the regular income
tax. e AMT allows fewer exemptions, deductions, and
tax credits than the regular income tax does, and tax-
payers are required to pay the AMT if it is higher than
their regular tax liability. e 2017tax act temporarily
increases the income levels at which the AMT takes
eect. As a result, less income is subject to the AMT.
9. Taxable ordinaryincome is all income subject to the individual
income tax (other than most long-term capital gains and
dividends) minus adjustments, exemptions, anddeductions.
10. For more information, see “Key Methods at CBO Used
to Estimate the Macroeconomic Eects of the 2017 Tax Act”
(supplemental material for e Budget and Economic Outlook:
2018 to 2028, April 2018), https://go.usa.gov/xQcZD.
11. For discussion of that kind of taxation, see Congressional Budget
Oce, Taxing Businesses rough the Individual Income Tax
(December 2012), www.cbo.gov/publication/43750.
e changes to the AMT have eects similar to those
resulting from the reductions in statutory rates. However,
the eect on the labor supply is likely to be smaller,
because higher-income people, most of whom are already
working full time, are less likely to increase their supply
of labor than the population as a whole is.
Temporary Changes to the Standard Deduction and
Itemized Deductions. When preparing their income tax
returns, taxpayers may either take the standard deduc-
tion, which is a at dollar amount, or itemize—that is,
deduct certain expenses, such as state and local taxes,
mortgage interest, charitable contributions, and some
medical expenses. Taxpayers benet from itemizing
when the value of their deductions exceeds the standard
deduction. Under prior law, however, the total amount
of most itemized deductions was generally reduced by
3percent of the amount by which a taxpayer’s adjusted
gross income exceeded a specied threshold.
12
Other
restrictions applied to specic itemized deductions.
e 2017tax act nearly doubles the size of the standard
deduction and repeals the overall limit on itemized
deductions, but it also eliminates many small itemized
deductions and reduces the amounts that can be claimed
for two widely used deductions. First, deductions for
state and local taxes—the sum of property taxes and
either income or sales taxes—may not exceed $10,000.
Second, taxpayers may deduct the interest on no more
than $750,000 of home mortgage debt, a reduction from
$1.1million under prior law.
e combination of the higher standard deduction and
the restrictions on the two widely used deductions has a
number of eects:
•
e number of taxpayers itemizing deductions
is expected to fall from 49million in 2017 to
18million in 2018.
•
After-tax income changes for many taxpayers. e
increase in the standard deduction causes after-
tax income to rise for most taxpayers who did not
previously itemize deductions. After-tax income also
rises for some higher-income taxpayers, because the
eect of restricting the two widely used deductions
is oset by the repeal of the limit on total itemized
12. Adjusted gross income includes income from all sources not
specically excluded by the tax code, minus certain deductions.
113appendiX B: The eFFecTS oF The 2017TaX acT on cBo’S economic and BudgeT proJecTionS The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028
deductions. However, after-tax income falls for some
homeowners and residents of states and localities with
high taxes.
•
e restrictions aect the mix of investment.
By applying caps to state and local property tax
deductions and by limiting the amount of deductible
mortgage interest, the act reduces the incentive to
buy a house, or to invest in housing in other ways,
in relation to the incentive to make other kinds of
investment.
Temporary Repeal of Personal Exemptions and
Expansion of the Child Tax Credit. Under prior law,
taxpayers could generally claim a personal exemption for
themselves and each dependent. at exemption reduced
their tax burden. In addition, taxpayers with income
below specied thresholds were eligible for a tax credit
of up to $1,000 for each qualifying child under the age
of 17.
13
at credit was partially refundable (mean-
ing that eligible people received money back from the
government if the value of the credit was greater than the
amount of taxes that they owed).
e act repeals the personal exemption but doubles the
size of the maximum child tax credit for most eligi-
ble taxpayers; in addition, eligibility for the credit is
extended to include more higher-income taxpayers. e
maximum refundable portion is increased to $1,400.
Taxpayers can also claim a new $500nonrefundable tax
credit for each dependent who is not a qualifying child.
e eects of those provisions vary among groups of tax-
payers. After-tax income is projected to decline for most
taxpayers, including those without dependents who will
no longer benet from the personal exemption and many
other taxpayers for whom the expanded credits do not
compensate for the loss of the personal exemption. For
many lower-income taxpayers with children, however,
after-tax income will increase. at eect occurs because
many people with low income do not pay income taxes
and will therefore not be aected by the elimination of
the personal exemption but will still benet from the
expanded refundable credit if they have children.
13. For more information about the child tax credit, see
Congressional Budget Oce, Refundable Tax Credits (January
2013), www.cbo.gov/publication/43767.
Changing the Estate and Gi Taxes
e value of property transferred at death and of certain
gifts made during a person’s lifetime is subject to the
federal estate and gift taxes.
14
However, such transfers up
to a certain cumulative dollar amount are exempt from
taxation. e 2017tax act doubles the amount between
2018 and 2025.
at increase gives people a greater incentive to hold
assets and transfer them at death. In addition, the expira-
tion of the increase at the end of 2025 is likely to induce
people to make gifts before 2026.
Eliminating the Penalty for Not Having Health
Insurance
e Aordable Care Act includes a provision, generally
called the individual mandate, that requires most people
to have health insurance meeting specied standards
and that imposes a penalty on those who do not comply
(unless they have an exemption). Under prior law, the
size of the penalty was the greater of two quantities: a
xed amount specied in law, or a specied fraction of
a household’s income. e tax act reduces the size of the
penalty to zero, starting in 2019.
Because the size of the penalty increased with house-
hold income, it acted as a tax on income. In addition,
it encouraged some people to buy subsidized insur-
ance through the marketplaces established under the
Aordable Care Act; the result was that they faced higher
marginal tax rates, because those subsidies shrink as
income rises. Both of those eects discouraged work, so
the elimination of the penalty is projected to increase the
labor supply slightly.
15
In addition, eliminating the penalty is expected to make
insurance premiums in the nongroup market, where
insurance is purchased individually, higher than they
would otherwise have been. Insurers are required to
provide coverage to any applicant, and they cannot vary
premiums to reect enrollees’ health status or to limit
14. For more information about those taxes, see Congressional
Budget Oce, Federal Estate and Gift Taxes (December 2009),
www.cbo.gov/publication/41851.
15. For further discussion of those eects, see Edward Harris and
Shannon Mok, How CBO Estimates the Eects of the Aordable
Care Act on the Labor Market, Working Paper 2015-09
(Congressional Budget Oce, December 2015), www.cbo.gov/
publication/51065.
114 The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028 APRIL 2018
coverage of preexisting medical conditions. ose fea-
tures are most attractive to applicants with relatively high
expected costs for health care, so eliminating the penalty
will tend to reduce insurance coverage less among older
and less healthy people than among younger and health-
ier people, boosting premiums.
16
Requiring an Alternative Ination Measure to Adjust
Tax Provisions
Many parameters of the tax system are adjusted for ina-
tion, including the individual income tax brackets. ose
adjustments prevent a general increase in prices from
increasing taxes. Under prior law, most of those adjust-
ments were based on changes in the consumer price
index for urban consumers (CPI-U), which is a measure
of ination calculated by the Bureau of Labor Statistics
(BLS). Beginning in 2018, the measure used for adjust-
ing most parameters of the tax system will be changed to
the chained CPI-U. Whereas the CPI-U measures ina-
tion in the price of a xed “basket” of goods, the chained
CPI-U allows for adjustments in spending patterns by
consumers; also, unlike the CPI-U, it is little aected
by statistical bias related to the sample sizes BLS uses in
computing each index. For both reasons, the chained
CPI-U grows more slowly than the CPI-U does.
17
In
CBO’s projections, the former grows more slowly than
the latter by 0.25percentage points per year, on average.
e change in the measure of ination will increase
revenues because it will accelerate a phenomenon called
real bracket creep, in which income is pushed into higher
and higher tax brackets because it is rising faster than
ination. Real bracket creep results in individuals’ facing
higher marginal tax rates, so it reduces the incentive
to work. Unlike many of the tax act’s changes to the
individual income tax, this change is permanent, and the
resulting increase in revenues will grow over time.
In 2026, the temporary provisions of the act that push
down marginal tax rates will have expired. Because the
change in the measure of ination pushes up marginal
16. For more discussion, see Congressional Budget Oce, Repealing
the Individual Health Insurance Mandate: An Updated Estimate
(November 2017), www.cbo.gov/publication/53300.
17. For more information, see the testimony of Jerey Kling,
Associate Director for Economic Analysis, Congressional Budget
Oce, before the Subcommittee on Social Security of the House
Committee on Ways and Means, Using the Chained CPI to Index
Social Security, Other Federal Programs, and the Tax Code for
Ination (April 18, 2013), www.cbo.gov/publication/44083.
rates, the eective marginal rate on labor income will be
higher, beginning in that year, than it would have been
under prior law, CBO estimates.
How the Act Aects the Economic Outlook
In CBO’s projections, the eect of the 2017tax act is to
boost the average amount of real GDP by 0.7percent
over the 2018–2028period (see Table B-2). Real GDP
is boosted by 0.3percent in 2018 and by 0.6percent
in 2019, and the eect peaks at 1.0percent in 2022. In
later years, the eect is smaller, and by 2028it has fallen
to an increase of 0.5percent. at pattern arises because
the act’s eects on real GDP growth are positive initially
and then negative.
Like real GDP, real potential GDP is higher in every
year of the 11-year period because of the tax act. But
through 2022, the increase in real GDP is greater than
the increase in real potential GDP (see Figure B-1). e
result is that the positive output gap—the amount by
which real GDP exceeds real potential GDP—is larger
than it would have been otherwise. (Even without the
act, real GDP would have been greater than real poten-
tial GDP in CBO’s baseline projections.)
at larger output gap through 2022puts some upward
pressure on prices. Ination (as measured by the price
index for personal consumption expenditures) is pro-
jected to be slightly higher than it would have been
otherwise over the rst several years of the period and
then to be unchanged.
In CBO’s projections, the larger output gap and greater
inationary pressure prompt the Federal Reserve to
respond by pushing interest rates higher over the next
few years than they would have been without the tax act.
e rate for 3-month Treasury bills is higher by 0.5per-
centage points by 2022, and the rate for 10-year Treasury
notes is 0.2percentage points to 0.3percentage points
higher during the 2018–2022period. ose higher inter-
est rates and the end of the act’s cuts in personal income
taxes in 2025slow the growth of real GDP, reducing the
pressure on prices and interest rates. However, as a result
of greater federal borrowing and certain provisions of the
tax act that aect portfolio decisions, interest rates on
10-year notes are still slightly higher by 2028 than they
would have been otherwise.
e projected gains in output generate increases in
income for the employees and owners of the businesses
115appendiX B: The eFFecTS oF The 2017TaX acT on cBo’S economic and BudgeT proJecTionS The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028
Table B-2 .
Economic Eects of the 2017 Tax Act
Average
2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028
2018–
2022
2023–
2028
2018–
2028
Output (Percent)
Real GDP 0.3 0.6 0.8 0.9 1.0 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.6 0.6 0.5 0.7 0.7 0.7
Real potential GDP 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.6 0.8 0.7
Nominal GDP 0.4 0.8 0.9 1.1 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.1 0.9 0.8 0.8 0.9 1.0 0.9
Real GNP 0.1 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.4 0.4 0.4
Contribution of Components to Real GDP
(Percentage points)
Private consumption 0.4 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.8 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.6 0.6 0.6
Private nonresidential xed investment 0.2 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.4 0.2 0.3
Private residential investment * -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 * * * -0.1 -0.1 -0.1
Government consumption and investment ** ** 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 ** ** ** 0.1 0.1
Net exports -0.3 -0.3 -0.2 -0.2 -0.2 -0.2 -0.1 -0.1 ** ** 0.1 -0.2 * -0.1
Exports -0.2 -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 * * * ** ** ** ** -0.1 ** *
Imports
a
-0.1 -0.2 -0.2 -0.1 -0.1 -0.2 -0.1 -0.1 * ** ** -0.2 -0.1 -0.1
Potential Labor and Productivity (Percent)
Potential labor force 0.1 0.3 0.4 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.3
Potential average labor hours 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.1 * 0.3 0.2 0.2
Potential total labor hours 0.2 0.5 0.7 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.1 0.6 0.5 0.6
Potential labor productivity * -0.1 * ** 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.3 * 0.2 0.1
Employment and Unemployment
Total nonfarm employment (Percent)† 0.2 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.5 0.6 0.6
Unemployment rate (Percentage points) * -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 * * ** ** ** ** -0.1 ** *
PCE Price Level (Percent)
** ** 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.1
Interest Rates (Percentage points)
Federal funds rate 0.1 0.2 0.4 0.4 0.5 0.3 ** * * * ** 0.3 0.1 0.2
Three-month Treasury bills 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.4 0.5 0.3 0.1 * * * ** 0.3 0.1 0.2
Ten-year Treasury notes 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.1 ** ** ** ** ** 0.2 ** 0.1
International Measures
Net international lending as a percentage
of GDP (Percentage points) -0.4 -0.4 -0.4 -0.4 -0.5 -0.5 -0.4 -0.3 -0.2 -0.2 -0.2 -0.4 -0.3 -0.4
Net international income as a percentage
of GDP (Percentage points) -0.1 -0.2 -0.3 -0.3 -0.4 -0.4 -0.3 -0.3 -0.3 -0.3 -0.4 -0.3 -0.3 -0.3
Export-weighted exchange rate (Percent)
b
1.8 1.7 1.9 1.9 1.8 1.7 1.6 1.6 1.6 1.5 1.5 1.8 1.6 1.7
Memorandum:
Real GDP Growth (Percentage points) 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.1 * * -0.1 -0.2 -0.1 -0.1 0.2 -0.1 **
PCE Price Inflation (Percentage points) ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** * * ** ** **
Source: Congressional Budget Oce.
Real values are nominal values that have been adjusted to remove the eects of inflation.
GDP = gross domestic product; GNP = gross national product; PCE = personal consumption expenditures; * = between -0.05 percent or percentage points
and zero; ** = between zero and 0.05 percent or percentage points.
a. A negative value indicates an increase in imports.
b. A higher value indicates an increase in the exchange value of the dollar.
[†Values corrected on April 17, 2018]
116 The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028 APRIL 2018
that produce the output. So employees’ total compen-
sation rises in CBO’s projections, as do their wages and
salaries. (Total compensation includes not only wages
and salaries but also bonuses, stock options, benets, and
the employer’s share of payroll taxes for social insurance
programs.) Corporate prots and business income also
increase.
Other organizations have also estimated the economic
eects of the 2017tax act (see Box B-2). e forecasts
vary, but most show increases in the level of real GDP
over the rst few years and a more moderate increase
by2027.
Eects on Potential Output
Various provisions of the 2017tax act directly aect the
productive potential of the U.S. economy. ey do so
by promoting increases in investment and the potential
labor supply. e act is also projected to raise measured
total factor productivity, which is the average real output
per unit of combined labor and capital services. On net,
the act is projected to raise the level of potential output
throughout the 2018–2028period. e eect on poten-
tial output peaks at 0.9percent in the middle years of
the period and declines to 0.5percent in 2028. In CBO’s
projections, the act’s contribution to real GDP at the end
of the period results from an increase in the amount of
potential output.
Private Investment. Increases in investment boost
potential output by increasing the stock of capital
goods—structures, equipment, intangible assets, and
inventories—that are used to produce output. e
act aects private investment through three channels:
Figure B-1 .
Economic Eects of the 2017 Tax Act at a Glance
-1.0
-0.5
0
0.5
1.0
1.5
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0
0.1
0.2
Percent Percentage of Potential GDP
Percentage PointsPercent
The act boosts real GDP in relation to real potential GDP in the
near term.
That change creates additional excess demand in the
economy, raising the output gap, . . .
. . . putting some upward pressure on consumer prices, . . . . . . and pushing up interest rates.
1 2
3 4
All Other Eects
Eects of the
2017 Tax Act
3-Month
Treasury
Bills
Real GDP
Real Potential
GDP
10-Year
Treasury Notes
2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 2027
2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 2027
2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 2027
2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 2027
Source: Congressional Budget Oce.
Real values are nominal values that have been adjusted to remove the eects of inflation. Potential GDP is CBO’s estimate of the maximum sustainable
output of the economy. Excess demand exists when the demand for goods and services exceeds the amount that the economy can sustainably supply.
The output gap is the dierence between GDP and CBO’s estimate of potential GDP and is expressed as a percentage of potential GDP. Consumer
prices are measured by the price index for personal consumption expenditures.
GDP = gross domestic product.
117appendiX B: The eFFecTS oF The 2017TaX acT on cBo’S economic and BudgeT proJecTionS The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028
Box B-2 .
Comparison With Other Organizations’ Estimates
Various organizations other than the Congressional Budget
Oce have estimated the economic eects of the 2017 tax act.
In general, the organizations expect the act to increase the
level of real gross domestic product (GDP) throughout the peri-
ods that they examine. Many of the forecasts follow a pattern
similar to the one followed by CBO’s projections: increasing
positive eects on real GDP over the first several years, then a
moderation, and then a more muted eect by 2027.
In the organizations’ projections for the 2018–2022 period,
the act’s expected average eect on real GDP ranges from
0.3percent to 1.3 percent; CBO’s projection is 0.7 percent. For
the 2023–2027 period, the average eect ranges from 0.3 per-
cent to 2.9 percent; CBO’s projection is 0.8 percent. In 2027,
the projected eect ranges from −0.1 percent to 2.9 percent;
CBO’s projection is 0.6 percent.
CBO limited its comparison to forecasts that broadly exam-
ined the nal version of the tax act. Other forecasts examined
earlier versions of the act or only parts of it, so CBO did not
include them in the comparison.
Assorted Estimates of the Eects of the 2017 Tax Act on the Level of Real GDP
Percent
First Five Years
Tenth
Year Average
2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2027
2018–
2022
2023–
2027
2018–
2027
Moody's Analytics 0.4 0.6 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.3
Macroeconomic Advisers 0.1 0.3 0.5 0.6 0.6 0.2 0.4 0.5 0.5
Tax Policy Center
a
0.8 0.7 0.5 0.5 0.5 * 0.6 0.3 0.5
International Monetary Fund 0.3 0.9 1.2 1.2 1.0 -0.1 0.9 0.3 0.6
Joint Committee on Taxation – – – – – 0.1 to 0.2 0.9 0.6 0.7
Congressional Budget Oce 0.3 0.6 0.8 0.9 1.0 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.7
Goldman Sachs 0.3 0.6 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.6 0.7 0.7
Tax Foundation 0.4 0.9 1.3 1.8 2.2 2.9 1.3 2.9 2.1
Penn Wharton Budget Model – – – – – 0.6 to 1.1 – – –
Barclays 0.5 – – – – – – – –
Sources: Congressional Budget Oce and the organizations listed above.
Real values are nominal values that have been adjusted to remove the eects of inflation.
GDP = gross domestic product; –=not available; * = between -0.05 percent and zero.
a. Values are for scal years.
changes in incentives, crowding out (which occurs when
larger federal decits reduce the resources available for
private investment), and changes in economic activity.
18
18. CBO estimated the act’s eects on investment in 32 types of
equipment, 23 types of nonresidential structures, 3 types of IP
products, 3 types of residential capital, and inventories. For more
information, see “Key Methods at CBO Used to Estimate
the Macroeconomic Eects of the 2017 Tax Act” (supplemental
material for e Budget and Economic Outlook: 2018 to 2028,
April 2018), https://go.usa.gov/xQcZD.
Some of the changes to investment are nanced by
domestic investors and some are nanced by foreign
investors, resulting in changes to international invest-
ment ows.
In CBO’s projections, total business xed investment—
which consists of investment in nonresidential struc-
tures, equipment, and IP products—is higher in every
year from 2018 through 2028 than it would otherwise
have been. It is boosted by changes in incentives and
118 The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028 APRIL 2018
stronger economic activity but dampened by crowding
out from increased federal borrowing (see Figure B-2).
19
By contrast, residential investment is lower in every year
from 2018 through 2028 than it would otherwise have
been. Incentives to undertake residential investment are
reduced through 2025by limits on the deductibility of
property taxes and mortgage interest, as well as by fewer
households’ itemizing deductions. Residential investment
is reduced throughout the entire period by crowding out.
Changes in Incentives. e tax act aects investment
in the United States by changing incentives to invest,
including the user cost of capital and thus the minimum
return that an investment must achieve to be protable.
e act reduces the user cost of capital in various ways.
Some provisions do so by reducing statutory tax rates.
Extending bonus depreciation also reduces the user cost
of capital. However, the act increases the user cost of
capital for owner-occupied housing from 2018 through
2025 and for research and development beginning in
2022.
e act species several signicant changes in 2026that
aect the user cost of capital for pass-through businesses
and for homeowners. As a result, their response to the
19. e incentives and crowding out that aect business xed
investment also aect investment in inventories.
tax act depends partly on their expectations of future tax
policy. In CBO’s projections, 20percent of investment is
made by businesses and households that expect provi-
sions scheduled to end in 2026actually to do so, and
80percent of investment activity is consistent with the
provisions’ being extended.
20
(e act also includes some
less signicant changes in scal policy over the 11-year
period, and CBO incorporated the projection that all
businesses and households behave as if they expect those
changes to occur.)
e tax act aects the user cost of capital in dierent
ways for the three kinds of xed business investment and
for residential investment (see Figure B-3).
•
Investment in equipment is projected to benet the
most from changes in the user cost of capital because
of lower statutory tax rates and the extension of
100percent bonus depreciation through 2022. e
allowed amount of bonus depreciation declines over
the following several years, and by 2027, the increase
20. ose projections of expectations are based on historical
responses to extensions of major tax provisions. For more
information, see “Key Methods at CBO Used to Estimate
the Macroeconomic Eects of the 2017 Tax Act” (supplemental
material for e Budget and Economic Outlook: 2018 to 2028,
April 2018), https://go.usa.gov/xQcZD.
Figure B-2 .
Eects of the 2017 Tax Act on Business Fixed Investment
Billions of Dollars
Page 1 of 1
Crowding Out
-60
-40
-20
0
20
40
60
80
100
2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 2027
Changes in
Incentives
Changes in
Economic Activity
Business xed investment is greater
through 2028 because the positive
eects of changes in incentives and
economic activity oset the negative
eects of crowding out.
Source: Congressional Budget Oce.
Business fixed investment is businesses’ purchases of equipment, nonresidential structures, and intellectual property products. The changes in
incentives consist of changes in the user cost of capital, which is the gross pretax return on investment that provides the required return to investors
after covering taxes and depreciation, and changes in the benets of locating business establishments in the United States. Changes in economic
activity consist of changes in demand for goods and services and changes in the supply of labor. Crowding out occurs when larger federal decits
reduce the resources available for private investment.
119appendiX B: The eFFecTS oF The 2017TaX acT on cBo’S economic and BudgeT proJecTionS The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028
in investment that is due to changes in the user cost
of capital stems almost entirely from the reduction in
the corporate tax rate.
•
Investment in nonresidential structures also benets
from lower statutory tax rates. In addition, certain
types of structures with relatively short tax lives, such
as oil derricks, benet from bonus depreciation. But
by 2027, as with the previous category, the increase
in investment that is due to changes in the user cost
of capital stems almost entirely from the reduction in
the corporate tax rate.
•
Investment in IP products is boosted by changes
in the user cost of capital through 2021. However,
in contrast to its treatment of equipment, the tax
act makes depreciation less generous for R&D
and for software development beginning in 2022.
Consequently, starting in that year, investment in IP
products is lower than it would otherwise have been.
•
e bulk of residential investment is in owner-
occupied housing. e tax act increases the user cost
of capital for homeowners from 2018 to 2025by
limiting the deductibility of property taxes and
mortgage interest and by reducing the number of
households that itemize. at increase outweighs a
reduction in the user cost of capital for the people or
pass-through businesses that own most rental housing
and that will benet from lower individual tax rates
during that period. Beginning in 2026, the act has
little impact on the user cost of residential capital.
e tax act also increases incentives to invest in the
United States by encouraging rms to locate their estab-
lishments here. e primary means of encouragement is
the reduction in the statutory corporate tax rate in the
Figure B-3 .
Eects of the 2017 Tax Act on Investment Through Changes in Incentives
Billions of Dollars
-40
-20
0
20
40
60
-40
-20
0
20
40
60
2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 2027
Equipment
Nonresidential Structures
Intellectual Property
Products
Residential
Structures
The act’s changes in the tax treatment
of depreciation eventually reduce the
eects of incentives on investment in
equipment and intellectual property
products.
Limits on the tax deductibility of
payments for property taxes and
mortgage interest, along with a drop
in the number of households that take
itemized deductions, reduce spending on
residential structures through 2025.
Source: Congressional Budget Oce.
The changes in incentives consist of changes in the user cost of capital, which is the gross pretax return on investment that provides the required return
to investors after covering taxes and depreciation, and changes in the benets of locating business establishments in the United States.
120 The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028 APRIL 2018
United States. However, that eect is partly oset by
other changes. For example, the GILTI and FDII provi-
sions may increase the incentive to locate tangible assets
outside the United States.
Furthermore, although the increased incentives to locate
establishments in the United States will boost total
investment, that eect is muted by the amount of labor
available, in CBO’s estimation. In other words, barring
a change in the amount of labor supplied in the United
States, business location decisions are projected to have
only a limited eect on investment. at is because the
additional labor used by an establishment locating in the
United States is no longer available to other establish-
ments. So the increased investment by the new establish-
ment is partly oset by reduced investment by existing
establishments.
Crowding Out. CBO estimates that greater federal
borrowing ultimately reduces private investment. When
the government borrows, it borrows from people and
businesses whose savings would otherwise be nancing
private investment. Although an increase in government
borrowing strengthens the incentive to save, the resulting
rise in saving is not as large as the increase in government
borrowing; national saving, or the amount of domes-
tic resources available for private investment, therefore
falls. However, private investment falls less than national
saving does in response to government decits, because
the higher interest rates that are likely to result from
increased federal borrowing tend to attract more foreign
capital to the United States. In CBO’s assessment, the
crowding out of private investment occurs gradually, as
interest rates and the funds available for private invest-
ment adjust in response to increased federal decits.
e reduction in private investment resulting from
crowding out occurs primarily because of higher interest
rates, so the eects on dierent categories of investment
depend on how sensitive they are to interest rates. In
general, interest rates constitute a larger share of the user
cost of capital for types of capital that depreciate slowly,
so changes in interest rates have a larger eect on invest-
ment in those types of capital. For example, a 1percent
rise in mortgage rates would have a larger impact on
residential investment than a 1percent rise in corpo-
rate bond rates would have on businesses’ purchases of
computers. Consequently, investment in residential and
nonresidential structures bears a disproportionate share
of the impact of larger decits. e act’s crowding-out
eects vary not only by type of investment but also as
time passes; the strongest eects occur in 2022, when the
act’s eects on the decit are largest (see Figure B-4).
Changes in Economic Activity. When demand for their
output increases, businesses invest in capital to meet
that additional demand; the expanded investment then
increases the potential output of the economy, because
a larger capital stock increases the businesses’ ability to
produce output. e impact on investment is greatest
during the period in which demand is accelerating. Once
businesses have invested enough to meet the additional
Figure B-4 .
Eects of the 2017 Tax Act on Investment Through Crowding Out
Billions of Dollars
Page 1 of 1
-30
-25
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 2027
Equipment
Nonresidential Structures
Intellectual Property Products
Residential
Structures
The reduction of investment resulting
from crowding out is greatest in 2022,
when the eects of the act on the
federal decit are the largest.
Source: Congressional Budget Oce.
Crowding out occurs when larger federal decits reduce the resources available for private investment.
121appendiX B: The eFFecTS oF The 2017TaX acT on cBo’S economic and BudgeT proJecTionS The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028
demand, the only further stimulus to investment is the
need to gradually replace the additional capital.
In CBO’s projections, the tax act increases demand
primarily by increasing households’ demand for goods
and services over the next few years, widening the output
gap. Consequently, rms engage in investment to meet
that demand beyond what they would do in response to
changing tax incentives. e act’s eect on investment
through that channel is positive during the period when
the output gap is growing more rapidly than it would
have in the absence of the act and negative when it is
growing less rapidly.
e act is also projected to expand investment through
another change in economic activity: increasing the labor
supply. Businesses must purchase additional capital for
the new workers to use. However, because rms adjust
their stocks of capital more slowly than they adjust the
number of their employees, the response of investment
to changes in the labor supply is gradual.
How the Increase in Investment Is Financed. e projected
increase in U.S. investment would be nanced by private
domestic and foreign saving. In CBO’s projections, the
private domestic saving rate initially rises in response to
the higher after-tax rates of return on U.S. investment
resulting from the tax act. In addition, because the act
boosts U.S. economic output, national income rises,
and total private domestic saving grows. (However,
some portion of the increased private domestic saving
is used to nance increased federal borrowing, reducing
the amount of saving available for private investment.)
Earnings subject to deemed repatriation are expected to
be used primarily to reduce corporate debt and thus to
contribute only slightly to nancing the increase in pri-
vate investment (see Box B-1 on page 109). Meanwhile,
increases in the rate of return on investment in the
United States in relation to the rate in other countries
will attract additional inows of foreign saving. CBO
estimates, therefore, that a substantial portion of the
increase in private investment will be nanced through
those inows.
Potential Labor Supply. In CBO’s projections, the
2017tax act also boosts potential output by increasing
the potential supply of labor through increases in the
potential labor force participation rate and in hours
worked per worker. e potential labor force participa-
tion rate is higher by an annual average of 0.2 percentage
points during the 2018–2028 period; the peak eect is
0.3 percentage points in 2023 and 2024.
Total potential hours worked, the result of increases
in both the potential labor force participation rate
and average weekly hours, rise by an annual average of
nearly 0.6percent. e peak increase in potential hours
worked—more than 0.8percent—occurs in 2023; by
2028, the eect has dwindled to about 0.1percent. CBO
estimates that more than half of the projected eects on
the overall potential labor supply result from increases in
the potential labor force participation rate. e remain-
der result from increases in average weekly hours.
21
ose eects occur because the tax act changes incentives
to work, particularly by lowering statutory individual
income tax rates and by making other changes that lower
marginal tax rates through 2025.
22
In the following
years, however, most of the relevant provisions that lower
tax rates expire, and marginal rates will be higher than
under prior law, primarily because of the new measure
of ination that the act species for adjusting various
parameters of the tax system. As a result, the act reduces
incentives to work in those years. An exception is the
act’s elimination of the penalty for not having health
insurance. at elimination is permanent, so its eect on
the potential labor supply—slightly increasing it, in part
because the size of the penalty increased as household
income increased, causing it to act as a tax on income—
is projected to be permanent.
CBO expects that it will take time for people to respond
to provisions in the act. e agency’s estimates therefore
account for the time that it takes for people to under-
stand the act’s eects and to make adjustments in how
much they work. For example, the estimates reect the
speed with which people are expected to increase their
supply of labor in response to lower tax rates in the early
years of the 11-year period and to decrease that supply
after provisions expire later on.
21. Even if that estimate of the relative shares were dierent, the
estimated change in total potential hours worked would not
change, and therefore the estimate of potential output would not
either.
22. For more information, see “Key Methods at CBO Used
to Estimate the Macroeconomic Eects of the 2017 Tax Act”
(supplemental material for e Budget and Economic Outlook:
2018 to 2028, April 2018), https://go.usa.gov/xQcZD.
122 The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028 APRIL 2018
Also, as with expectations about capital costs, CBO
incorporated the projection that 20percent of people
anticipate the scheduled expiration of many of the bill’s
provisions in 2025. ose people respond by supplying
more labor in the years when tax rates are scheduled
to be temporarily low. ey also begin reducing their
supply of labor even before the rates are scheduled to
increase, because such adjustment is costly. People who
are projected to be surprised by the act’s change in tax
rates have more muted responses to the lower rates before
2025 and also a more muted response to the increase
afterward. Taken together, over the 11-year period,
CBO’s projections of the average labor response to the
tax act are not much aected by the agency’s projections
of people’s dierent expectations.
Potential Productivity. Over the rst few years of the
2018–2028period, CBO projects, the 2017tax act
will not have much net eect on potential labor pro-
ductivity, which is dened as real potential output per
potential hour of labor (see Table B-2 on page 115). If
the contribution of capital to output rises more than the
contribution of potential hours of labor, potential labor
productivity rises. At rst, the act is projected to boost
hours and capital by similar amounts, so the eect on
potential labor productivity is small. But in later years,
the contribution of capital to output has increased more
than the contribution of potential hours, and by 2027,
potential labor productivity is increased by 0.3percent.
Because the increase in the level of potential labor pro-
ductivity is roughly unchanged between 2027 and 2028,
it has little eect on potential output growth by the end
of the 11-year period.
e act is also projected to raise potential output slightly
by discouraging prot-shifting strategies that histori-
cally have suppressed measured total factor productiv-
ity. e act is expected to encourage rms to claim as
domestic production the services of IP that were pre-
viously claimed as production abroad (see Box B-3 on
page 124). In CBO’s estimation, even though the rms
made that claim, those services have been and continue
to be generated by IP assets that are included in estimates
of the domestic capital stock. As a result, the shift in the
reported location of services associated with that IP will
result in an increase in measured domestic output even
though there is no corresponding increase in measured
domestic inputs of labor or capital. Another way of look-
ing at the shift is that more reported production is being
generated by the same measured amount of labor and
capital. at is the denition of an increase in total factor
productivity. CBO has therefore adjusted its projections
of potential total factor productivity by only a slight
amount each year to account for the anticipated increase
in output that is not matched by an increase in inputs.
Eects on Actual Output
In CBO’s projections, the 2017tax act boosts the
demand for goods and services, accelerating the growth
of actual output in relation to the growth of potential
output over the rst half of the 2018–2028period. As
a result, the output gap is 0.1percentage point larger
between 2018 and 2022 than it would have been other-
wise, on average. Heightened overall demand is projected
to increase consumer spending, increase employment
further above CBO’s estimate of its potential level,
reduce net exports (that is, exports minus imports), and
slightly increase ination. However, because most pro-
visions of the act that relate to individual income taxes
expire and thus subtract from overall demand after 2025,
the output gap is 0.1percentage point smaller in 2026
and slightly smaller in 2027 than it would have been
otherwise.
Consumer Spending. e eect of the act on real GDP
over the next few years derives largely from its impact on
consumer spending. e act reduces individual income
tax revenues, increasing households’ disposable income
and thereby their spending. e changes to individual
income taxes include temporary changes to tax rates,
the standard deduction, the personal exemption, the
child tax credit, itemized deductions, and the alternative
minimum tax.
Higher- and lower-income households adjust their
spending dierently, on average, in response to such
increases in disposable income. CBO accounted for
those dierences by assessing the distribution of tax cuts
among income groups.
23
In CBO’s assessment, lower-
income households spend a larger share of the additional
income in such cases than higher-income households do.
CBO’s estimate of the overall eect on consumer spend-
ing also incorporates the agency’s assessment of the act’s
23. For more information, see “Key Methods at CBO Used
to Estimate the Macroeconomic Eects of the 2017 Tax Act”
(supplemental material for e Budget and Economic Outlook:
2018 to 2028, April 2018), https://go.usa.gov/xQcZD.
123appendiX B: The eFFecTS oF The 2017TaX acT on cBo’S economic and BudgeT proJecTionS The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028
impact on equity and housing wealth. In CBO’s projec-
tions, lower corporate taxes contribute to the boost in
consumer spending by increasing the after-tax earnings
of businesses, thereby raising the equity wealth of busi-
nesses’ shareholders. Countering that eect are the act’s
changes related to the standard deduction for individuals
and to the treatment of state and local taxes and mort-
gage interest deductions, which are expected to make
house prices lower than they would be otherwise. CBO
does not expect the provisions that govern repatriation of
businesses’ foreign earnings to aect consumer spending
signicantly (see Box B-1 on page 109).
Furthermore, CBO’s estimate of the act’s impact on
consumer spending accounts for the elimination of the
penalty for not having health insurance. at change
means that people will be less likely to obtain coverage,
decreasing subsidies and aecting consumer spending.
Analysis of the act’s eect on consumer spending is com-
plicated by the fact that most of the changes to individ-
ual income taxes are scheduled to end after 2025. What
people expect about expirations matters; a change in dis-
posable income that they consider transitory is likely to
aect their spending less than one that they expect to last
longer. In CBO’s projections, about 80percent of con-
sumer spending is undertaken by people who believe that
the individual income tax cuts will be extended beyond
2025, and the remainder is undertaken by people who
believe that they will end as scheduled. (ose specica-
tions are analogous to what CBO used for expectations
of scal policies aecting decisions to work and invest.)
But CBO’s estimate of the overall change in consumer
spending in the next few years would not change very
much if the agency used dierent specications, because
the expectations in this case relate to relatively distant
events.
In later years, the end of most provisions related to
individual income taxes slows the growth of consumer
spending. In CBO’s projections, those changes subtract
from disposable income and overall demand in 2026
and2027.
Net Exports. In the near term, the act is projected to
boost real imports, reduce real exports, and therefore
lower real net exports. In CBO’s projections, imports
rise in the near term because the act raises the domestic
demand for goods and services. For example, the capital
investment stimulated by the act will raise demand for
imported capital goods (such as computers and machine
tools) and for imported materials (such as steel and
aluminum). Furthermore, when the domestic economy
is operating above its potential, as it is in CBO’s projec-
tions, additional increases to production are costly and
dicult, making the propensity to import goods and ser-
vices particularly strong. And higher domestic demand
can push exports down as rms concentrate on satisfying
that demand.
In addition, CBO expects the act to moderately increase
the exchange value of the dollar in 2018 (see Table B-2
on page 115).
24
Increased demand for U.S. assets,
which results mainly from the increase in the rate of
return on those assets, strengthens the dollar in CBO’s
projections. at stronger dollar causes export prices
to rise and import prices to decline. Consequently, real
exports decrease, real imports increase, and real net
exports fall.
CBO expects the act’s initial eects on real net exports to
begin to dissipate after 2019. One reason is that the act’s
eect on the exchange value of the dollar is projected
to gradually decline after 2020. In addition, the expi-
ration of the cuts in individual income taxes dampens
consumer spending and thus imports. By 2026, CBO
expects the act’s eect on real net exports to disappear.
e Labor Market. Over the next few years, the wider
output gap, and the resulting increase in demand for
labor and upward pressure on wages, are projected to
raise employment and hours worked further above
CBO’s estimate of their potential levels. e agency
expects the tax act to initially lower the unemploy-
ment rate by a small amount, slightly widening the gap
between that rate and the natural rate of unemploy-
ment over the 2018–2022 period. (e natural rate of
unemployment is the rate of unemployment that results
from all sources except uctuations in overall demand.)
e unemployment rate is projected to be, on average,
0.1percentage point lower—and the labor force partic-
ipation rate and total hours worked to be, respectively,
0.2percentage points and 0.7percent higher—than they
would have been otherwise between 2018 and 2022.
24. CBO’s measure of the exchange value of the dollar is an export-
weighted average of the exchange rate indexes between the dollar
and the currencies of leading U.S. trading partners. An increase
in that measure indicates that the dollar is appreciating.
124 The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028 APRIL 2018
Box B-3 .
The Eects of Profit Shifting on Economic Statistics
The prot-shifting strategies used by multinational corporations
(MNCs) aect many economic indicators. All of the strategies
distort data about U.S. taxable income by inflating reported
foreign income while reducing reported domestic income. But
the strategies alter other statistics in dierent ways.
Although the 2017tax act includes a number of provisions that
discourage prot shifting, it may encourage some prot shifting
by exempting foreign dividends from U.S. taxation. On net, the
Congressional Budget Oce projects, the changes in tax law
will reduce profit shifting by roughly $65billion per year, on
average, over the next 11years. Most of that projected reduc-
tion can be attributed to less use of the debt allocation and
intellectual property (IP) transfer strategies discussed below.
1
Locating MNCs’ Debt in High-Tax Countries. By allocating
a greater share of debt, and the associated deduction for
interest payments, to high-tax countries, an MNC can reduce
the amount of taxable income reported in those high-tax
countries.
2
In CBO’s projections, the reduction in profit shifting
through decisions about debt location accounts for about half
of the $65billion total reduction in profit shifting resulting from
the tax act.
When a U.S. aliate of an MNC borrows from a foreign bank
on behalf of the entire MNC (thus allocating debt to the United
States), that loan shows up in U.S. international investment
position accounts as an increase in foreign-owned U.S. assets.
The result is a reduction in the United States’ net international
investment position.
Locating debt in the United States can alter net international
lending—which is national saving minus domestic investment—
if that debt is borrowed from foreign investors. Net interna-
tional lending is also equal to the sum of net international
income (which is the dierence between the income earned by
1. MNCs use many strategies to shift prots to low-tax countries. For purposes
of simplication, CBO has categorized all of them into the three types
described here.
2. The same incentive exists for a variety of other costs that benet an MNC,
such as costs for headquarters. CBO focuses on debt both because it is the
mechanism that this strategy usually employs and because the choice of
where to locate debt has economic eects that are similar to those resulting
from the use of the other mechanisms.
U.S. residents from foreign sources and the income earned by
foreign individuals from U.S. sources) and net exports (which
are exports minus imports). The reason that locating debt in
the United States aects net international lending is that the
reduction in the U.S. net international investment position
leads to a reduction in net international income. Because
there is no corresponding change in net exports, net interna-
tional lending declines, along with gross national product. But
because reported production is unaected, gross domestic
product (GDP) is unchanged.
The act’s reduction in the U.S. corporate tax rate, combined
with the new rules governing the deduction of interest, will
reduce some use of this strategy. Before the act was enacted,
a relatively high statutory tax rate made the United States an
attractive location for debt. But now, because the United States
is unlikely to continue to be the highest-taxed jurisdiction for
many MNCs, some will move their debt to aliates in countries
with a higher corporate tax rate.
Transferring Intellectual Property. When an MNC moves its IP
from an aliate in a high-tax country to an aliate in a low-tax
country, that MNC can report less of its taxable income in the
high-tax country and more in the low-tax country. CBO projects
that the tax act’s reductions in profit shifting through the trans-
fer of IP will account for roughly one-third of the total projected
reduction in profit shifting over the next 11years.
Prot shifting through the international transfer of IP distorts
real U.S. product statistics (that is, statistics adjusted to remove
the eects of inflation) and real GDP. Royalties and other
revenues derived from IP are counted in the national income
and product accounts—ocial U.S. accounts that track the
amount and composition of GDP, the prices of its components,
and the way in which the costs of production are distributed as
income—as real production of IP services. When IP assets are
transferred from the United States to another country, the real
services derived from those assets are attributed not to the
United States but to the other country, so real net exports and
real GDP are reduced. However, unlike locating debt in high-
tax countries, transferring IP has no eect on net international
lending, because any reductions to net exports associated
with IP transfers are matched by an additional dollar of net
international income.
Continued
125appendiX B: The eFFecTS oF The 2017TaX acT on cBo’S economic and BudgeT proJecTionS The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028
CBO estimates that the reduction in the U.S. corporate tax
rate, combined with the new rules governing the treatment of
income from high-return investments (much of which is derived
from IP), will reduce corporations’ incentives to shift profits by
transferring IP outside the United States. However, that eect
is expected to be modest. IP is especially easy to relocate, so
MNCs are typically able to locate it in whichever aliates face
the lowest tax rate on the income that it generates. Because
tax havens outside the United States will continue to have
relatively low tax rates, CBO projects that most IP currently
located there will remain there. For newly created or future
IP, the changes resulting from the tax act and the xed costs
of transferring IP to foreign aliates will probably deter some
small amount of prot shifting.
Setting Transfer Prices. MNCs can reduce their U.S. taxes by
strategically setting transfer prices—the prices that aliates of
the same MNC charge each other across national boundaries.
3
To minimize prots earned in high-tax countries, MNCs can
systematically overstate the prices that aliates in high-tax
countries pay for imports from foreign aliates and understate
the prices that aliates in high-tax countries charge for exports
3. Technically, transferring IP to aliates in low-tax countries can also be
categorized as strategically setting transfer prices. However, prot shifting
through IP transfers and prot shifting through setting the transfer prices of
tangible assets distort statistics in dierent ways.
to foreign aliates.
4
CBO projects that reduced prot shifting
through that strategy will account for only a small portion of
the projected $65billion annual reduction in profit shifting.
That strategy tends to distort reported economic statistics
about trade prices: In CBO’s view, the ocial U.S. export price
indexes are lower than they would have been otherwise, and
import price indexes are higher. Those inaccuracies distort
overall U.S. price indexes that use trade prices as an input,
such as the GDP deflator.
By distorting economic statistics about trade prices, the stra-
tegic setting of transfer prices also aects the national income
and product accounts. The strategy leads nominal exports to
be understated and nominal imports to be overstated, thereby
reducing ocial measures of net exports and nominal GDP.
Strategically setting transfer prices alters the composition of
net international lending. But like transfers of IP, the strategy
has no eect on the total amount of net international lend-
ing, because each dollar that the strategy removes from net
exports is oset by a dollar of foreign profit added to net inter-
national income. And because transfer prices do not aect total
national income, gross national product (the sum of domestic
income and net international income) is likewise unchanged.
4. MNCs are required to set transfer prices similar to the prices that would
be paid for goods and services in market-based transactions. However, for
some traded goods and services, it is dicult to find comparable market
prices. For those transactions, MNCs have more leeway to strategically set
transfer prices to minimize tax liability.
Box B-3. Continued
The Eects of Profit Shifting on Economic Statistics
And nonfarm employment is projected to be, on aver-
age, about 0.6percent higher over the 11-year period,
representing about 0.9 million jobs (see Table B-2 on
page 115).*
Ination. CBO expects the 2017tax act to have a
positive but small eect on consumer price ination
over the next few years. at expectation results from
CBO’s estimates that the act will only slightly widen the
gap between the actual and natural rates of unemploy-
ment and that the link between general price ination
and labor market conditions has been weak in recent
years. In addition, the act is expected to slow growth in
the prices of imported goods, slightly dampening the
inationary pressure from labor markets, particularly in
the near term. Finally, expectations of ination, which
have been low and relatively stable since the late 1990s,
are expected to remain close to the Federal Reserve’s
long-run goal in the coming years, as consumers and
businesses expect the central bank to successfully adjust
monetary policy to prevent ination from deviating
excessively from its target.
25
As a result, core PCE ination—that is, ination for
personal consumption expenditures, excluding prices for
25. For more information, see “Key Methods at CBO Used
to Estimate the Macroeconomic Eects of the 2017 Tax Act”
(supplemental material for e Budget and Economic Outlook:
2018 to 2028, April 2018), https://go.usa.gov/xQcZD.
[*Values corrected on April 17, 2018]
126 The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028 APRIL 2018
food and energy—is expected to be very slightly higher
each year between 2018 and 2025. e total PCE price
index is expected to rise slightly more quickly than that,
as is the consumer price index; both are projected to be
higher by 0.1percent through 2023, on average, than
they would have been in the absence of the act and to be
higher by 0.2percent in 2028.
Eects on Interest Rates
In response to the projected widening of the output gap
and the greater inationary pressure, CBO expects the
Federal Reserve to raise short-term interest rates more
rapidly over the next few years than it would have if the
2017tax act had not been enacted. As a result, the fed-
eral funds rate (the interest rate that nancial institutions
charge each other for overnight loans of their monetary
reserves) is projected to be 0.5percentage points higher
in 2022 than it otherwise would have been. e faster
increase in interest rates is expected, in turn, to restrain
the boost in output by dampening consumption and
investment spending, thereby limiting the increase in
demand for labor and keeping ination close to the
central bank’s long-term goal. CBO’s projections include
a slight and temporary reduction in short-term interest
rates by the Federal Reserve in response to the end of
most of the act’s individual income tax provisions after
2025, but there is no net eect on short-term rates by
the end of the 11-year period.
e eects on long-term interest rates follow a similar
pattern. However, because long-term rates are partly
determined by the average of expected short-term rates,
the eect on long-term rates is larger initially but more
muted overall.
CBO’s projections of interest rates over the 11-year
period are also based on the agency’s projections of a
number of factors that aect the interest rates of U.S.
Treasury securities over the longer run. On net, those
factors are projected to result in rates of longer-term
Treasury notes that are somewhat higher as a result of the
tax act, even as rates of shorter-term Treasury securities
are roughly unaected. In CBO’s projections, factors
that increase the interest rates of Treasury securities over
the period include the increase in federal borrowing and
the increase in the after-tax rate of return on capital.
Additional factors that increase the rates of longer-term
Treasury securities include the reduction in companies’
holdings of such securities following deemed repatria-
tion of foreign holdings and an increase in the premium
incorporated in the rates of such securities. e tax act
increases that premium in CBO’s projections because
with greater upward pressure on ination, longer-term
Treasury securities become less valuable as a hedge
against unexpectedly low ination. e main factor that
decreases the interest rates of Treasury securities over the
period is the increase in net foreign investment.
26
Eects on Income
e economic eects of the tax act include not just
greater GDP but also higher overall income. Domestic
income that derives from the production of goods and
services—for labor, employees’ compensation and their
wages and salaries; for businesses, corporate prots and
proprietors’ income—is projected to rise with GDP.
Flows of net international income also change, reecting
the tax act’s eects. And businesses see changes in income
in addition to those associated with production, which
will aect taxable business income.
Employees’ Compensation and Wages and Salaries.
Employees’ total compensation in the economy behaves
in a pattern similar to that projected for total GDP. Over
the 2018–2028period, the act is projected to increase
such compensation by an annual average of 0.9percent;
the peak eect is 1.0 percent in 2023. Average total
wages and salaries follow a similar pattern—gaining
0.9percent, on average, and peaking at an increase of
about 1.1percent in 2023.
Corporate Prots and Proprietors’ Income. In CBO’s
projections, domestic corporate prots increase over the
11-year period, becoming 7.1percent larger in 2028
than they would have been without the 2017tax act.
e increase occurs partly because of greater total GDP
and partly because of lower net interest payments by
corporations. at second eect happens for two reasons.
First, corporations are expected to reduce their debt and
interest payments in response to the act’s less favorable
treatment of interest costs. Second, corporations are esti-
mated to have held debt in the United States to nance
domestic investment while they had substantial holdings
of foreign prots. As those prots are repatriated, the
corporations are expected to reduce their debt and inter-
est payments (see Box B-1 on page 109).
26. For more information, see “Key Methods at CBO Used
to Estimate the Macroeconomic Eects of the 2017 Tax Act”
(supplemental material for e Budget and Economic Outlook:
2018 to 2028, April 2018), https://go.usa.gov/xQcZD.
127appendiX B: The eFFecTS oF The 2017TaX acT on cBo’S economic and BudgeT proJecTionS The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028
In addition, the change in the deductibility of net oper-
ating losses alters taxable corporate income. e act lim-
its the deductibility of those losses, so corporate income
rises. But they may be deducted from future income, so
the act largely alters when taxable corporate income will
be reported rather than permanently increasing it.
In CBO’s projections, nonfarm proprietors’ income rises
by 1.2percent over the 2018–2022period before falling
back to a 0.3percent gain by 2028, roughly following
the pattern projected for overall economic activity. Over
the 2018–2028period, the increase averages 0.9percent.
Prot Shifting and Foreign Income. e act includes
changes to the treatment of international income that
will aect how multinational corporations shift their
prots among aliates in order to lower their tax liabil-
ities. ree of the most widely used prot-shifting strat-
egies are locating debt in aliates in countries with high
corporate income tax rates, transferring intellectual prop-
erty, and strategically setting transfer prices (the prices
that aliates charge each other across national boundar-
ies; see Box B-3 on page 124). Such prot shifting dis-
torts the national income and product accounts—ocial
U.S. accounts that track the amount and composition
of GDP, the prices of its components, and the way in
which the costs of production are distributed as income.
Prot shifting also lowers taxable corporate income in
the United States—by roughly $300billion each year,
recent estimates from the economic literature suggest.
27
CBO attributes most of that amount to decisions about
the location of debt and transfers of IP.
27. at estimate was informed by CBO’s calculations and by
Fatih Guvenen and others, Oshore Prot Shifting and Domestic
Productivity Measurement, Working Paper 23324 (National
Bureau of Economic Research, April 2017), www.nber.org/
papers/w23324; Kimberly A. Clausing, “e Eect of Prot
Shifting on the Corporate Tax Base in the United States and
Beyond,” National Tax Journal, vol. 69, no. 4 (December 2016),
pp. 905–934, http://dx.doi.org/10.17310/ntj.2016.4.09;
Kimberly A. Clausing, e Eect of Prot Shifting on the Corporate
Tax Base in the United States and Beyond (available at SSRN,
November 2015, updated June 2016), pp. 905–934, http://
dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2685442; and Gabriel Zucman,
“Taxing Across Borders: Tracking Personal Wealth and Corporate
Prots,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 28, no. 4 (Fall
2014), pp. 121–148, http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jep.28.4.121.
For a discussion of prot shifting and taxable income, see
Congressional Budget Oce, An Analysis of Corporate Inversions
(September 2017), www.cbo.gov/publication/53093.
In CBO’s projections, the provisions of the tax act reduce
prot shifting and the resulting statistical distortions,
on net. at change in the reported location of prots is
expected to result in an increase in taxable income even
though there is no direct increase in measured income
from domestic inputs of labor or capital. All told, the
reduction in prot shifting raises income reported in
the United States by roughly $65billion each year,
on average, in CBO’s projections over the 11-year
period. Changes in the location of debt and transfers
of IP account for most of that reduction in total prot
shifting.
Eects on Gross National Product. e 2017tax act is
expected to aect GDP and GNP dierently. It raises
the projected level of real GDP by an annual average
of 0.7percent over the 11-year period, an increase of
about $710per person (in 2018dollars). Real GNP, by
contrast, increases by 0.4percent, on average, or about
$470per person.
28
e act is expected to increase GNP
less than it increases GDP because it shrinks U.S. net
international income (see Table B-2 on page 115).
ere are two reasons for that decline in net income
ows to the United States. First, the increase in foreign
investment in the United States that is associated with
greater private investment and increased government
borrowing generates a fall in net international lending,
which is national saving minus domestic investment.
29
In CBO’s projections, the act decreases net international
lending over the next 11years by an average of 0.4per-
cent of GDP (see Figure B-5). e additional income
generated by the foreign investment in the United States
accrues to foreign investors.
e second reason is that the act alters the rates of return
earned on international assets. As the after-tax prot-
ability of U.S. investments rises because of the taxact,
foreign investors earn a higher return on their U.S.
assets. In addition, the reported rate of return that U.S.
investments earn abroad will decline after 2023 as the act
28. e peak eects for the per-person amounts occur in 2024,
at $900for real GDP per person and $640for real GNP per
person; by 2028 the amounts are $550for real GDP per person
and $250for real GNP per person.
29. In the national income and product accounts, net international
lending is called “net lending to the rest of the world.” Over most
of the past 40years, it has been negative, indicating that the
United States is a net borrower. CBO projects that net lending
will remain negative from 2018 through 2028.
128 The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028 APRIL 2018
discourages U.S. companies from shifting their taxable
income from the United States to aliates in foreign
countries. By altering the relative rates of return on inter-
national assets through those changes, the act reduces net
international income and shrinks the dierence between
GDP and GNP.
How the Act Aects the Budget Outlook
e 2017tax act had signicant eects on CBO’s bud-
getary projections for the 2018–2028period. e agency
took two steps to incorporate those eects into the
projections. First, CBO estimated the act’s direct eects,
which are the eects on the budget that do not take
into account any changes to the aggregate economy. For
example, this step incorporated the ways in which the
act’s reduction in tax rates will diminish federal revenues
through its eects on taxpayers’ behavior. Second, CBO
considered macroeconomic feedback—that is, the ways
in which the act will aect the budget by changing the
overall economy (such as by increasing wages, prots,
and interest rates). Incorporating both kinds of eects
boosts the projected primary decit by a cumulative
$1.272trillion over the course of the 11-year period.
After debt service too is incorporated, the projected de-
cit is higher by $1.854trillion (see Table B-3).
Before incorporating macroeconomic feedback, CBO
estimates that the tax act would increase the primary
decit by a cumulative $1.843trillion over the 11-year
period—increasing it through 2026 and decreasing
it thereafter.
30
ose decit increases would increase
debt-service costs in every year and by growing amounts
that total $471billion over the period.
ose increases would be partially oset by macroeco-
nomic feedback. In CBO’s projections, macroeconomic
feedback reduces the primary decit by a cumulative
$571billion over the 2018–2028period. at reduction
mainly results from the act’s boost to taxable income,
which increases revenues. e eects on the primary
decit, like those on taxable income, are largest in the
early years, peaking in 2019 and then getting smaller.
Macroeconomic feedback also raises debt-service costs
through two partly osetting eects: e reduction in
the primary decit lowers federal borrowing and thus
debt-service costs, but the act also leads to higher interest
rates and thus increases the cost of federal borrowing.
30. ose direct eects on the primary decit primarily reect the
cost estimate produced by the sta of the Joint Committee on
Taxation. See Joint Committee on Taxation, Estimated Budget
Eects of the Conference Agreement for H.R. 1, the “Tax Cuts And
Jobs Act,” JCX-67-17 (December 18, 2017), https://go.usa.gov/
xQczr (PDF, 37 KB). However, in contrast to the cost estimate,
the estimates reported in this appendix extend through 2028 and
include debt-service costs. e direct eects shown in Table B-3
also reect a number of technical revisions. e sources of those
revisions include information about the implementation of the
tax act learned in recent months.
Figure B-5 .
Eects of the 2017 Tax Act on Net Foreign Transactions
Percentage of Gross Domestic Product
Growth in the federal decit and
in investment increase borrowing
from foreigners, which reduces net
international income.
Page 1 of 1
Net International
Lending
Net International
Income
-0
.6
-0
.4
-0
.2
0
0.2
2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 2027
Source: Congressional Budget Oce.
Net international income is the dierence between the income earned by U.S. residents from foreign sources and the income earned by foreign
individuals from U.S. sources. Net international lending is a measure that summarizes a country’s transactions with the rest of the world; it consists of
net exports, net international income, and net transfers.
129appendiX B: The eFFecTS oF The 2017TaX acT on cBo’S economic and BudgeT proJecTionS The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028
On net, macroeconomic feedback from the act raises
projected debt-service costs by $110billion over the next
11years.
Uncertainty Surrounding CBO’s Estimates
CBO’s estimates of the economic and budgetary eects
of the 2017tax act are subject to signicant uncertainty.
e agency is particularly uncertain about how the act
will be implemented; what policies state governments
and foreign countries might change in response to the
act; what expectations people have about future scal
policy; how businesses will rearrange their nances in the
face of the act; how households, businesses, and foreign
investors will respond to changes in incentives to work,
save, and invest in the United States; and how changes in
economic activity will aect labor and capital income.
Implementation
How the Treasury ultimately implements the tax act will
partly determine how businesses and households respond
to the various provisions. For example, CBO’s projec-
tions of the new deduction for owners of pass-through
businesses incorporate the expectation that the Treasury
will be able to enforce the limits that the act places on
the types of income that are eligible for the deduction.
States’ and Foreign Countries’ Responses
If state governments and foreign countries change their
own scal policies in unanticipated ways in response to
the tax act, those changes will have implications for the
act’s economic and budgetary eects. For example, many
state governments could choose not to incorporate some
of the act’s provisions—such as those involving personal
deductions and bonus depreciation—in their own tax
systems. at step would signicantly aect how house-
holds and rms chose to adapt to the changes. Foreign
governments might reduce their corporate tax rates or
adjust their tax rules in unanticipated ways in response
to the changes in U.S. tax law. In particular, if foreign
governments signicantly lowered their tax rates on cor-
porate income, that would dampen net inows of foreign
capital. In addition, foreign governments are expected
to challenge several of the new tax rules with the World
Trade Organization. If those challenges are broadly suc-
cessful, the United States could be subject to retaliatory
taris unless the tax provisions were changed.
Table B-3 .
Contributions of the 2017 Tax Act to CBO’s Baseline Budget Projections
Billions of Dollars
Total
2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028
2018–
2022
2018–
2028
Eects Without Macroeconomic Feedback
a
Eects on the Primary Deficit
b
194 281 307 304 263 218 183 164 36 -60 -46 1,349 1,843
Eects on Debt-Service Costs 3 8 17 29 39 48 55 63 68 70 71 97 471
Eects on the Deficit
c
197 289 325 333 302 266 238 227 104 10 25 1,445 2,314
Eects of Macroeconomic Feedback
a
Eects on the Primary Deficit
b
-33 -67 -65 -58 -55 -49 -47 -49 -48 -50 -51 -278 -571
Eects on Debt-Service Costs 0 5 12 18 23 27 23 13 3 -4 -11 59 110
Eects on the Deficit
c
-33 -61 -53 -41 -31 -22 -24 -36 -44 -54 -62 -219 -461
Total Contributions to Baseline Projections
Eects on the Primary Deficit
b
160 214 243 246 208 169 136 115 -12 -110 -97 1,071 1,272
Eects on Debt-Service Costs 3 14 29 47 63 74 78 76 71 66 60 156 582
Eects on the Deficit
c
164 228 272 292 271 243 214 191 59 -43 -37 1,226 1,854
Source: Congressional Budget Oce.
a. Macroeconomic feedback refers to the ways in which the act would aect the budget by changing the economy.
b. The primary decit is the decit excluding debt-service costs.
c. Positive numbers indicate an increase in the decit; negative numbers indicate a decrease in the decit.
130 The BudgeT and economic ouTlook: 2018 To 2028 APRIL 2018
People’s Expectations
In CBO’s projections, 20percent of households and
businesses expect scal policy to change over the 2018–
2028period as the tax act species; others are surprised
by those changes. Such expectations can have important
eects on how households and businesses respond to the
act. For example, if more people expect the reduction in
individual income tax rates to be temporary, as the act
species, more may shift their supply of labor from later
years into the years before rates are scheduled to go up.
If that happened, the timing of CBO’s projections would
change, but the average eect over the 11-year period
would not be strongly aected.
Prot Shiing by Multinational Corporations
e eect of the tax act’s international provisions on
prot shifting by multinational corporations is particu-
larly uncertain. One source of uncertainty is the pro-
visions’ complexity, which makes it dicult to predict
how and when corporations might respond to them.
CBO is also uncertain about how foreign governments
might change their tax rules in response to the act. For
instance, those governments might lower their own
corporate income tax rates to better compete for interna-
tional investment; that change would dampen the act’s
expected eect on prot shifting. And CBO is uncertain
about whether the provisions will be deemed compliant
with international rules.
Decisions to Work, Save, and Invest
Many economic eects of the new legislation stem from
its eects on individuals’ decisions to work and save
and on businesses’ decisions to invest. CBO’s estimates
of those eects reect the agency’s assessment of how
changes in individual and corporate tax rates aect the
supply of labor and the user cost of capital, as well as
its assessment of how changes in individuals’ disposable
income and wealth aect consumer spending. CBO
tries to produce assessments that lie in the middle of the
distribution of possible outcomes. But if fewer people
than CBO expects respond to lower marginal tax rates by
participating in the labor force, for example, the boost
in potential GDP will likewise be smaller than CBO pro-
jects. Another example involves the expected response of
international investors to the reduction in U.S. corporate
tax rates. If they increase investment more than CBO
expects, capital stock will increase more and the eects
on actual and potential output will be larger.
Some eects may dier from CBO’s assessments because
those eects may depend on economic conditions in a
way that the agency has not incorporated. For example,
CBO has not accounted for the extent to which the act’s
limits on the deductibility of net operating losses could
discourage investment more during periods of economic
weakness than in periods of economic strength. (e
eect of those limits is uncertain for other reasons as
well. For example, they could dampen the positive incen-
tives to invest that result from other provisions in the tax
act, a possibility that CBO has not accounted for in its
projections.)
Changes in Economic Activity
CBO projects that the tax act will increase labor income
and capital income, boosting demand for goods and
services over the next several years. But demand may
respond more or less to those changes in income than
CBO estimates. Moreover, the changes in economic
activity resulting from the act may have smaller or larger
eects on businesses than CBO estimates. For example,
if businesses increase investment more than expected in
response to increases in economic activity, labor produc-
tivity and wages will rise faster than they do in CBO’s
projections.